Archive for March, 2017
Five things I think I think about the next phase of health care reform
Photo by Jon Collier
This is not the end of Obamacare; it’s the beginning
In a surprising move, Paul Ryan pulled the American Health Care Act, the Republican ACA repeal and replace bill, last Friday. It had become clear that there was no movement to the left or the right that would garner enough votes to allow passage in the House. Even if it had passed in the House by moving right, much of that movement was likely to be stripped out in the Senate, where the Republican majority is slimmer, but no less internally conflicted. The president has stated he is moving on to other issues like tax reform and infrastructure building.
So you might think that health care reform on the federal level is done for now. Whether that is true or not, it is also pretty clear to me that there is still a great deal of work to do to stabilize and improve the ACA. Cost constraints are still lacking, and insurance marketplaces at the state level are still suffering from shrinking insurer participation. While coverage has vastly improved under the ACA, affordability remains elusive if you don’t qualify for a subsidy.
Where are we going next? Some (including me) are hoping that this opens the door to real bipartisan negotiation. Here’s the theory. The Trump administration cares about the appearance of winning, not ideology. If you can’t work over the Freedom Caucus to get the votes, you go to the Tuesday Group, a group of moderate Republicans. Perhaps they’ll even appeal to the next group over from them, moderate Democrats, to get onboard for something.
Here are five things I observed from this last round of negotiations:
- The Freedom Caucus has a literal interpretation of the phrase “repeal and replace”. All the rhetoric about removing Obamacare “branch and root”? Turns out it wasn’t simply rhetoric for them. They believe that Medicaid expansion to childless adults must be removed entirely, because it is enabling able-bodied citizens to get care without working for it. All the headlines about 24 million more uninsured shocked many of us, but for conservatives was actually not a bad thing, and for some a desired outcome, judging from the rhetoric surrounding the debate.
- Loss aversion works. One of the truisms of behavioral economics is that fear of loss is about three times as motivating as desire for gain. This has been shown over and over again by people like Amos Teversky and Danny Kahnemann in psychology experiments. Thus, some people didn’t like the Affordable Care Act until they faced the possibility that they would lose coverage if it was repealed. For the first time in years, public approval of the ACA is greater than disapproval. (By the way, now that the immediate threat of repeal is gone, I predict those numbers will reverse again.) If you want people to value something, don’t try to sell it to them; give it to them and then try to take it away (the Classic Coke strategy).
- Trying to sneak legislation through in the age of Twitter is like trying to sneak to the bathroom in your pajamas through Grand Central Station. Hiding stuff so you don’t get criticized for it doesn’t work. Nor does speeding up timelines for the same purpose. We may have to do this a few more times before people get it, but the old days of passing legislation that hasn’t been dissected under a microscope I think are gone. There are too many smart people out there with time on their hands and a Twitter following to feed. They have an immediate platform to do the Roman thumbs up or down on literally everything in view, and are just waiting for something to tweet about.
- The emerging centrist view is that we need to maintain coverage for everybody who has it now, but get to cost containment to make the system sustainable. In a previous post, I talked about the hard truths that both sides are avoiding by blaming the other guy. But what do we do to control costs? The conservative answer is market forces, and the progressive one is government regulation. Neither one has a great track record when it comes to health care. So what’s an industrial superpower to do? There was funding in the ACA to set up CMMI, and much of their work has been on alternative payment models intended to bend the cost curve over time. But pragmatically the experience has been mixed for medical homes, bundled payment, and population-based payment. Rollout has been slower than many would like, and affect too few providers to declare it a success. I would love to see a real and thoughtful bipartisan discussion on some hybrid possibilities.
- And there is no guarantee the next move is toward bipartisanship. Winston Churchill said, “Americans will always do the right thing—after exhausting all the other possibilities.” If the last twenty years teaches us anything, it’s that governing from the extremes doesn’t work very well. So you’d think that the next move would be to try to govern from the center. But this is one of those Clayton Christiansen moments. Christiansen says that the winners of the last game are unlikely to be the inventors of the new game, since the new game displaces the old one. The existing game goes like this:
- Point out what’s wrong with any plan offered by your opponents, which is much easier to figure out than how to make things work (boring). It also gets a lot more attention on Twitter. And, the bonus is that you get to go home to your district and tell people you stood on principle, and that everyone else has the morals of a used car salesman.
- Foment anger and frustration, and promise that you are the only person capable of breaking through the mess. Do this, while you are all the while perpetuating the mess.
- Repeat, and fund-raise.
Both parties have had the chance to be in the majority and the minority in the last two decades, and both have gotten pretty good at the existing game. It will take a sea change to find the next game that rewards centrist compromise. Here’s hoping we exhaust all the other possibilities sooner rather than later.
CBO score shows 24 million more uninsured by 2026 under AHCA
Photo by Andrew Malone
Getting everyone into the tent proves trickier than anticipated
On the surface, it can be confusing what Republicans are trying to accomplish with their recently introduced American Health Care Act (AHCA). After all, no one consciously drafts a plan to reduce coverage and raise premiums; the ever-rising cost of health care will do that quite well on its own. The CBO score shows higher costs in the near term, but then a 10 percent reduction in projected average premiums vs. the status quo in 2026. CBO also projects that we will have 52 million uninsured in 2026, or an increase of 24 million over today. As discussed in a previous post, for progressives this is ideologically unacceptable since they consider health care to be an absolute right. Others with concerns likely fear the use of the increased number of uninsured as a campaign issue in the next election cycle.
Well, exactly what were the drafters trying to accomplish? As we discussed in a previous post, many of the maneuvers in AHCA are purposed to draw in young, healthy people into the insurance pool, in order to offset the cost of older and sicker people. In the conservative view, it is wrong for government to mandate the purchase of health insurance; instead, the product must be made attractive enough that young invincibles buy it voluntarily. The increase in the allowed rating multiple from 3:1 to 5:1 does this, since having older people pay more means younger people pay less. Another measure is the $100 billion Patient and State Stability Fund, which is money in the bill that is likely to be used by some states to make reinsurance payments to health plans, thereby lowering everybody’s premiums somewhat.
So could that work? It’s possible to make insurance more affordable for the young by taking those steps, in my opinion. The problem is that those actions also have other consequences:
- First, when you shift the cost of insurance away from the young and healthy, you have to put it somewhere, and that appears to be to the old and sick. Premium projections for poor 60 year olds net of subsidies go up by about $10,000 a year. For someone in this working poor group, the premium could be half of their entire salary. As a result, CBO projections suggest that the uninsured rate for those age 50-64 making <$30K/yr. will rise from 12% to an impressive 30% of the population. Again, no plan is able to take the same benefits and make the cost lower for everyone; if somebody pays less, somebody else has to pay more. In essence, some of the people you were trying to subsidize in the first place end up uninsured as a consequence of the effort to make it more affordable for the young invincibles.
- Second, the CBO projections say that by 2020, about 9 million fewer people will be buying coverage in the individual market. By 2026, those losses shrink to 2 million less, but this is largely because the CBO anticipates some employers stopping providing insurance as a benefit altogether, shifting people from employer-sponsored insurance to the individual market. The CBO agrees that more young people will sign up, but that will be more than offset by older people dropping coverage because they simply cannot afford it. The reasons are complicated, but have to do with the CBO’s lack of confidence that the penalties in the AHCA for being uninsured will be as compelling as the individual mandate in the ACA.
The AHCA still has to work its way through more committees before it makes its way to the floor of the House. There may still be amendments and revisions along the way. There is even talk about a “sidecar” bill addressing sale of insurance across state lines and association health plans. But currently, this shift of cost from younger and healthier to older and sicker is a big issue for Democrats and moderate Republicans (not to mention AARP, who have termed the AHCA an “age tax”). That, in addition to the substantial increase in the uninsured rate, makes this bill tough to swallow for a broad swath of Congress and its constituents. Whether it can survive with this shift is something that will be hotly debated in the next couple of weeks before Congress’ Easter recess.
It’s here, it’s here, the House Republican ACA repeal and replace bill!
How it’s evolved since A Better Way
House Republicans released their draft of the ACA repeal and replace bill, the American Health Care Act, they have been working so hard on. To the surprise of many, several parts of the ACA that were in question (esp. the first two) survive in this bill:
- Essential health benefits, including maternity care
- Prohibitions on annual and lifetime limits
- Dependent coverage until age 26
- No raising rates for pre-existing conditions
- Medicaid expansion through 2020
In addition, there were things expected that didn’t materialize (both of which might be inappropriate in a budget reconciliation bill):
- Sale of insurance products across state lines
- Association health plans
In a prior post, I talked about high-risk pools, and how simply segregating people with high cost doesn’t change the overall amount paid for the care, just how the cost for that care is redistributed. What this is looking more and more like, in my opinion, is very similar coverage paid for through alternative mechanisms. Because AHCA repeals all of the ACA’s taxes on the wealthy and industry, this largely results in substantial tax relief for the wealthy, and additional cost for the sick and the poor.
In addition, since AHCA allows the premium multiple for older people to be as much as five times that for the young, older Americans on average are likely to see rising premiums, while younger ones will see reductions in prices. Again to cite the prior post, this and continuous coverage provisions are how Republicans seek to draw young invincibles into the pool, without an individual mandate.
All in all, this bill seems to me to be much closer to what John Boehner said a few weeks ago at HIMSS: “They’re basically going to fix the flaws and put a more conservative box around it.” There are ideologic points made in it. They did get rid of the individual and employer mandates, and replaced it with a 30% premium penalty for going without insurance and then enrolling when you get sick. The jury is out on whether that’s a strong enough incentive to maintain continuous coverage, as the Republicans hope. But if the penalty is only 30% for a year, then a young invincible could go without coverage and make up the penalty by staying healthy for a mere four months. Why would I buy insurance under that scenario, until I absolutely needed it? That then risks setting off a death spiral, where there are not enough healthy people in the pool to offset the cost of the sick.
Various organizations are reporting big increases in premiums are the likely result of the tax credit levels proposed, netted against the subsidies that will be lost on the exchanges, especially for older and sicker adults. Defenders of AHCA seem to imply that these increases will be offset by the appearance of cheaper policies that are the result of lifting many of the essential benefits provisions of the ACA and the formation of high risk pools. But again, recall that high risk pooling doesn’t lower overall cost per se, only who pays and how much. And as we saw at the beginning of this piece, many of the provisions that raised the cost of ACA-compliant policies are still in AHCA.
The early reporting on AHCA is that neither moderate nor conservative Republicans are happy with the bill (Democrats are counted as an automatic no). Almost certainly there will be revisions as the relevant committees get to dissect it and weigh in with changes. But it is likely that movement to the left will strengthen resolve on the right, and vice versa. The window of acceptability to both poles is likely pretty narrow, if indeed it exists at all.
Boehner says you can’t repeal and replace quickly—and he’s tried
Winning was easy. Governing’s harder.—Cabinet battle #1, Hamilton the musical
In one of the more surreal moments lately (and there have been a few), former Speaker of the House John Boehner said at HIMSS 2017 that Republicans would not be able to repeal and replace the Affordable Care Act. Here’s the quote:
The irony of this is that it was probably politically impossible for him to say that while he was Speaker. There is a scene from the Aaron Sorkin drama The West Wing in which a political consultant chides one of the characters for resolving what would have been a juicy campaign issue. “You don’t want the money, you want the issue.” The ACA was too juicy an issue to resolve in the simple manner Speaker Boehner describes, and that many of my Republican friends have been advocating for, for years. Resolving it would have removed a campaign issue that was a slam-dunk-automatic-applause-getter winner for Republicans in this last election cycle. You don’t want to resolve the issue; you want angry voters mobilized against the other guy.
But like the proverbial dog that caught the car it was chasing, it isn’t clear what Republicans can actually do quickly to unravel the complexities of the ACA. I think the ACA probably deserves a fair amount of criticism for its complexity, but then again, the issue of sustainable health coverage in the era of billion dollar medical miracles is, well, pretty complex. You want to make things affordable, but you also want to give people comprehensive coverage so they don’t worry they’ll lose everything they have in a single medical event. If you ask the American public which one they want, they’ll say, “Both, of course!” Me too. But that involves getting healthy people to buy insurance, while guaranteeing everyone can buy it, while subsidizing a fairly large segment of the population that can’t afford to be as sick as they are. Each of these aims works against the other two.
It strikes me that the hard reality of complex subjects in the nanosecond attention span world in which we live is this: it’s a lot easier in fifteen seconds to make something complex sound bad than it is to make it sound good. This is supported by a lot of neuroscience and behavioral science work in the last two decades that show that our first response to anything novel is to evaluate it as a threat, and then only when we’re sure it’s not, can we engage in rational thought. So guess which kind of problem governments typically are asked to solve?
So I don’t blame John Boehner for not saying what he said at HIMSS back when he was Speaker. After all, he didn’t make the rules, he just played the game as well as he could. The bigger question is, how do we reduce the reward for making complexity bad, and increase the reward for thoughtful problem-solving?
Is A Better Way Actually Better?
Is Paul Ryan’s world view a place we want to live? We’re about to find out.
Photo by Tony Alter
In the current debate over the Affordable Care Act’s repeal and replacement, we are watching the collision of two world views. While partisans on both sides are likely to disagree, here’s my mini sketch of each of those views:
Progressives
- Health care is a right. Everyone, regardless of ability to pay, has the right to whatever the rest of us have access to.
- The main cause of the high cost of health care is profiteering by health care companies, whether providers, pharmaceutical manufacturers, or insurance companies. If profit was eliminated and health care made a utility, it would be affordable for the average American.
- The influence of the free market should be minimized in health care, since that’s the source of that unreasonable profit in the first place. Lots of entities have made lots of money trying to avoid getting people necessary care, instead of providing it when it’s needed. That’s just wrong.
- Bigger insurance pools are better, because they are more stable, have economies of scale, and it’s easier to pay for new stuff when you can spread the cost over lots of people. The best insurance pool would be one big national pool with everyone in it. This is called a single payer solution.
- Government systems are less expensive and fairer than private systems, because there isn’t a profit in government enterprises. All that running away from expensive people that private insurances do? Government aren’t allowed to do that.
Conservatives
- Health care is a right, but it comes with responsibility, too. You should get access to care if you participate in the system. It’s your individual responsibility to take care of yourself so that you’re not needlessly draining our shared resources. This includes working to the degree possible so that you’re paying your own way as much as you can.
- The main cause of high cost in health care is overregulation and litigation. If health care weren’t so burdened by trying to prevent things that are almost never happen in the first place, and provide services you didn’t ask for, the cost would be much lower. That overregulation also stifles innovation and competition, which is what makes goods and services in this country affordable for the average person in most other industries.
- The road to restoring affordability is to unleash the power of the free market. First, make people spend more of their own money using Health Savings Accounts. Then they’ll care about the price of medical stuff, which they don’t right now because insurance pays for most of the cost. And people will only shop effectively if they’re spending their own money, not somebody else’s.
- If you truly can’t contribute to your own health care cost, we’ll give you the money to do it through refundable tax credits, and then you can shop for your own care. After all, who can shop for you better than you? Inevitably when government shops for you, they do a bad job and load a bunch of requirements and benefits in there that don’t address your individual circumstance. That’s waste, and it’s expensive.
- Private insurance is the best vehicle to cover everybody where possible. This is because private vendors respond to customer needs much more quickly and nimbly than governments can. Yes, there is profit in health care, and there should be. Why else would anyone redesign a system to make it more efficient, if they didn’t get profit as a reward? Price controls simply create more friction and waste in the market, as people will find a way to get what they want one way or another.
Who is right about this? Which world view is most true to reality? I think there are elements of truth to both points of view. But there are also a few inconvenient truths that neither side wants to acknowledge:
- For progressives, the profit in health care is a problem, but mostly they talk about that profit in drug/device companies and insurers. In fact, most of the profit in health care is in providers. For example, where are we more different from western Europe, the amount of stuff we use, or the prices of that stuff? It turns out that it’s the prices of the stuff that account for most of the cost variance. When you look at the amount of stuff we use like hospital days or doctor visits, we actually look pretty competitive vs. western Europe. This was the source of Uwe Reinhardt’s Health Affairs article in 2003 entitled, “It’s the Prices, Stupid”. Providers in our systems, whether doctors, nurses, or hospital administrators make much more than their counterparts in other countries, and that’s all loaded into the cost of insurance.
- For conservatives, the evidence that markets in health care operate like other goods is quite limited. Some will say: “Look at Lasik! Look at cosmetic surgery! You can’t tell me that medical services are that different.” They’re right, Lasik and cosmetic surgery in particular are a lot like other discretionary goods, say, the eyeglasses and make up they replace. You get to elect to use those goods or not, and you can shop for them by comparing prices for a standard, understandable service or set of services. But much of the rest of medicine isn’t that kind of shoppable service. Rolling into an emergency room, nobody comparison shops and asks to be taken to the next emergency room because of price. Then, after you start treatment, a lot of your purchasing decisions are made by your doctor, using your Mastercard (insurance) liberally. Not the price-regulating market proponents would like to see. Try this sometime: ask your doctor what a particular procedure or drug costs. Mostly you’ll get blank looks, or a reassurance that your insurance will pay for it. But actual prices, not so much.
- For everybody, the rapidly increasing cost of health care has a lot to do with our rapidly increasing ability to actually stave off death and cure stuff with technology in ways that are downright miraculous, in addition to insurance company profit and filling out forms for burdensome regulations. Stuff like being able to cure cancer or hepatitis C, or turn AIDS into a chronic disease. Would we be willing to forego such miracles to lower the cost of health care overall? Well, that depends, for many people, on whether they can see themselves having one of those diseases. If yes, then the billions spent to develop those treatments are well-spent. If you look at where the eye-popping drug costs are these days, they’re associated with just these kinds of miracles. The adult conversation we haven’t gotten to is how much of our GDP we should devote to such miracles that will benefit an unknown few of us who could be any of us, versus broad-based benefit for the many, like improving education.
It should therefore not be surprising that there is a royal disagreement in DC these days about whether/ how to repeal and replace the ACA. The ACA is founded on a progressive worldview, and the replacement will be founded on a conservative one. And conveniently, by arguing about whose view is right, we can pretend we don’t see any of the difficult issues above, and blame continuing price increases on flaws in the other guy’s theory. But if we are to get to coherent public policy, we will have to face those truths and make hard decisions as a society. Anybody on the left or the right who claims otherwise probably doesn’t have an acquaintance with these inconvenient truths.